Discuss the UNIDO approach of social-cost benefit analysis
Ans. Towards the end of the sixties and
in the early seventies two principal approaches for SCBA emerged: the UNIDO
approach and the Little- Mirrlees approach. This section discusses the UNIDO
approach; the following discusses the Little-Mirrlees approach.
The UNIDO method of project appraisal
involves five stages:
1. Calculation of financial profitability
of the project measured at market prices.
2. Obtaining the net benefit of project
measured in terms of economic (efficiency) prices.
3. Adjustment for the impact of the
project on savings and investment.
4. Adjustment for the impact of the
project on income distribution.
5. Adjustment for the impact of project
on merit goods and demerit goods whose social values differ from their economic
values.
Each stage of appraisal measures the
desirability of the project from a different angle.
The measurement of financial
profitability of the project in the first stage is similar to the financial
evaluation. So, skipping the first stage, the remaining stages are being
discussed here.
Net benefit in terms of
economic (efficiency) prices
Stage two of the UNIDO approach is
concerned with the determination of the net benefit of the project in terms of
economic (efficiency) prices, also referred to as shadow prices.The UNIDO
approach suggests three sources of shadow pricing,depending on the impact of
the project on national economy. A project as it uses and produces resources
may for any given input or output (i)increase or decrease the total consumption
in the economy, (ii) decrease or increase production in the economy, (iii)
decrease imports or increase imports, or (iv) increase exports or decrease
exports.If the impact of the project is on consumption in the economy the basis
of shadow pricing is consumer willingness to pay. If the impact of the project
is on production in the economy, the basis of shadow pricing is the cost of
production. If the impact of project is on international tradeincrease in
exports, decrease in imports, increase in imports, or decrease
in exports— the basis of shadow pricing
is the foreign exchange value.
Shadow pricing of tradable inputs
and outputs: A good is fully
traded when an increase in its consumption results in a corresponding increase in
import or decrease in export or when an increase in its production results in a
corresponding increase in export or decrease in import. For
fully traded goods, the shadow price is
the border price, translated in domestic currency at market exchange rate. The
above definition of a fully traded good implies that domestic changes in demand
or supply affect just the level of imports or exports.
Non-tradable inputs and outputs: A good is non-tradable when the following
conditions are satisfied: I) its import price (CIF price) is greater than its
domestic cost of production and (ii) its export price (FOB price) is less than
its domestic cost of production.
The valuation of non-tradables is done as
per the principles of shadow pricing discussed earlier. On the output side, if
the impact of the project is to increase the consumption of the product in the
economy, the measure of value is the marginal consumers’ willingness to pay; if
the impact of the project is to substitute other production of the same
nontradable in the economy, the measure of value is the saving in cost of production.
On the input side, if the impact of the project is to reduce the availability
of the input to other users, their willingness to pay for the
input represents social value; if the
project’s input requirement is met by additional production of it, the
production cost of it is the measure of social value.
Externalities: An externality, also referred to as an
external effect, is a special class of good which has the following
characteristics: (i) It is not deliberately created by the project sponsor but
is an incidental outcome of legitimate economic activity, (ii) It is beyond the
control of the persons who are affected by it, for better or for worse. (iii)
It is not traded in the market place.
An external effect may be beneficial or
harmful. Examples of beneficial external effects are:
(i) An oil company drilling in its own
fields may generate useful information about oil potential in the neighbouring
fields.
(ii) The approach roads built by a
company may improve the transport system in that area.
(iii) The training programme of a firm
may upgrade the skills of its workers thereby enhancing their earning power in
subsequent employments.
Examples of harmful external effects are:
(i) A factory may cause environmental
pollution by emitting large volume of smoke and dirt. People living in the
neigbourhood may be exposed to health hazards and put to inconvenience.
(ii) The location of an airport in a
certain area may raise noise levels considerably in the neighbourhood.
(iii) A highway may cut a farmer’s
holding in two, separating his grazing land and his cowsheds, thereby adversely
affecting his physical output.
Since SCBA seeks to consider all costs
and benefits, to whomsoever they may affect, external effects need to be taken
into account. The valuation of external effects is rather difficult because
they are often intangible in nature and there is no market price, which can be
used as a starting
point. Their values are estimated by
indirect means.The above examples serve to emphasize the difficulties in
measuring external effects. In view of this, some economists have suggested
that
these effects be ignored. In order to
justify their suggestion, they argue that since a project is likely to have
both beneficial and harmful external effects, one may not err much in assuming
that the net effect would be zero. This argument, seemingly a rationalization
for one’s ignorance,
lacks validity. External effects must be
taken into account wherever it is possible to do so. Even if these effects
cannot be measured in monetary terms, some qualitative evaluation must be
attempted.
Measurement of the impact on
distribution
Stages three and four of the UNIDO method
are concerned with measuring the value of a project in terms of its
contribution to savings and income redistribution. To facilitate such
assessments we must first measure the income gained or lost by individual
groups within the society.
For income distribution analysis, the
society may be divided into various groups. The UNIDO approach seeks to
identify income gains and losses by the following: (i) Project, (ii) Other
private business, (iii) Government,(iv) Workers, (v) Consumers, (vi) External
sector.
There are, however, other equally valid
groupings.
The gain or loss to an individual group
within the society as a result of the project is equal to the difference
between shadow price and market price of each input or output in the case of
physical resources or the difference between price paid and value received in
the case of financial transaction.
Savings impact and its value— Most of the developing countries face scarcity
of capital. Hence the governments of these countries are concerned about the
impact of a project on savings and its value thereof.Stage three of the UNIDO
method, concerned with this, seeks to answer the following questions:
(i) Given the income distribution impact
of the project what would be its effect on savings?
(ii) What is the value of such savings to
the society?
Impact on savings of a project is equal to
ΣΔYiMPSi
where, ΔYi = change in income of group i as a result of the project
MPSi = marginal
propensity to save of group i
Value of savings of a rupee is the present value of the
additional consumption stream produced when that rupee of savings is invested
at the margin. The additional stream of consumption generated by a rupee of investment
depends on the marginal productivity of capital and the rate of reinvestment
from additional income. If the marginal productivity of capital is r and the
rate of reinvestment from additional income a, the additional stream of
consumption generated by a rupee of investment can be worked out. The
consumption stream starts with r (1 – a) and grows
annually at the rate of ar forever. Its
present value when discounted at the social discount rate k is:
I =r (1 - a)/(1 + k) +r (1 - a) (1 + ar)/(1
+ k)2 + … + r (1 - a) (1 + ar)n-1/(1
+ k)n + …
=r ((1 - a)/(1 + k))/1 – (1 + ar)/(1 + k)
=r (1 - a)/(k - ar)
where, I = social value of a rupee of
savings (investment)
r = marginal productivity of capital
a = reinvestment rate on additional
income arising from investment
k = social discount rate.
Income distribution impact— Many governments regard redistribution of
income in favour of economically weaker sections or economically backward
regions as a socially desirable objective. Due to practical difficulties in
pursuing the objective of redistribution entirely through the tax, subsidy, and
transfer measures of the government, investment projects are also considered as
instruments for income redistribution and their contribution toward this goal
is considered in their evaluation. This calls for suitably weighing the net
gain or loss by each groups, measured earlier, to reflect the relative value of
income for different groups and summing them.
Adjustment for merit and demerit
goods
In some case, the analysis has to be
extended beyond stage four to reflect the difference between the economic value
and social value of resources.This difference exists in the case of merit goods
and demerit goods. A merit good is one for which the social value exceeds the
economic value.
For example, a country may place a higher
social value than economic value on production of oil because it reduces
dependence on foreign supplies. The concept of merit goods can be extended to
include a socially desirable outcome like creation of employment. In the
absence of the project, the government perhaps would be willing to pay
unemployment compensation or provide mere make-work jobs. In the case of a
demerit good, the social value of the good is less than its economic value. For
example, a country may regard alcoholic products as having social value less
than economic value.The procedure for adjusting for the difference between
social value and economic value is as follows:
(i) Estimate the economic value.
(ii) Calculate the adjustment factor as
difference between the ratio of social value to economic value and unity.
(iii) Multiply the economic value by the
adjustment factor to obtain the adjustment.
(iv) Add the adjustment to the net
present value of the project as calculated in stage four.
Good work
ReplyDeleteVery Good
ReplyDeleteToo good n very helpful. Thnk q so much!
ReplyDeleteThank you for this.Finally i understood UNIDO approach
ReplyDeleteVery clear
ReplyDeletethanks!
ReplyDeleteNice work
ReplyDelete